Previous Page  30 / 56 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 30 / 56 Next Page
Page Background

Delivering the scale and breadth

of change needed to grow

our natural wealth—contributing

to biodiversity, water quality,

air quality, public health, and

flood management—will require

widespread action and investment

in land-use change. However,

the environment is made up of

complex, interwoven systems.

Changing one piece of the puzzle

can have myriad effects, often

with unexpected consequences.

This complexity has led Governments to split

up the problem, dealing with aspects of the

natural environment one-by-one: action for

wetland wildlife is often separate from work

on water quality, which is separate again from

flood risk alleviation. While not all solutions to

environmental problems require an integrated

approach (for example, if a wetland species is

declining due to factor unrelated to its habitat,

like overharvesting or lead poisoning) many of

them do. Lack of integration can be seriously

inefficient, leading to costly, short-term, and

untargeted projects.

Effective environmental improvement will

require joined-up action, using local knowledge

to improve whole environmental systems:

a landscape or catchment approach. Part of

the answer will be creating and protecting

new areas of high-quality habitats, like large

wetlands, but just as important will be changing

the way we manage the wider landscape.

Achieving change will sometimes need

regulation, but this should be complemented

by fairer financial incentives that reward land

managers who invest in our natural wealth. At

the moment, good land management often

goes unrewarded. Farmers who invest in

nature receive some money from the Common

Agricultural Policy (CAP), but many ways of

investing in natural wealth are not remunerated.

Where farmers are willing to use their fields for

flood storage, or to create wetlands to filter our

water, then we need to recognise that they are

delivering a service and afford them a long-

term, secure income for doing so.

For example, flood prevention funding is

often allocated inefficiently. Projects that

would deliver multiple benefits are overlooked

because funding tends to be issue-specific,

short-term, poorly focused and based on

conventional cost-benefit analysis. We know

that natural approaches, working alongside

conventional flood defences, can deliver flood

reduction benefits, but these benefits are

widespread and long-term. They need to be

incentivised for the long-term, sometimes on

large-scale.

So, to link up local knowledge with national

priorities, coordinate different objectives

and commission and reward change across

the landscape, we propose new Catchment

Commissioners.

Commissioners will be a lynchpin in

local investment in nature, creating new

commercial opportunities for investment

in natural capital. Long-term revenues for

natural capital investment will help land-

managers to diversify the income they

receive from managing their land well.

5(*,21$/ $&7,21

Catchment Commissioners